Brendan Burgess
Founder
- Messages
- 53,770
Yes I got that wrong. The transferable votes are not 1 quota but 2 quotas! I am reworking it.Hi Duke
I don't fully follow Scenario 1.
But FF does not get 3 quotas.
John got 3 quotas. Neither FF nor John get to choose what happens his other two quotas. The voters for John do.
Say John gets 1500 votes and the quota is 500
Mary gets no first preferences but 500 second preferences
Peter gets no first preferences but 500 second preferences
500 are non transferable
Joe gets 400 first preferences but no second preferences
The TV in Ireland is Surplus /Transferables which is 1000/1000 So Mary and Peter get 500 each.
The TV in Scotland would be Surplus/Total vote which is 1000/1500 = .66 So Mary and peter get 333 each and the 333 are not transferred.
If those who voted for John gave 750 2nd preferences each to Mary and Peter, then they would get 500 each and that would be fair enough.
Yes there is a gearing of your vote if you form part of a surplus to be transferred. One might regard that as a moral bonus for voting down the card, but hardly more democratic.Replying to comments saying that the Irish system is plain wrong, and illogical, I wanted to make this list of advantages for how we do it. You could make another list for the Scottish system too.
1. Voters are encouraged to fill out their ballots, which is good for PR.
What is at stake is how much of your vote should be transferred or more precisely what are your chances of being transferred? See below.2. A non-transferable vote cannot dilute a transferrable vote in surplus when being transferred. (E.g if surplus is 1, which arose from 1000 non-transferable and 1 transferable, then 1 full vote is transferred. It is not wasted or diminished just because others have not specified a no.2. This is not the case when total vote is the denominator in surplus calculation)
That is true for both systems. What is at stake is how much of your vote should be transferred. Under the Irish system you effectively get the value of more than one vote.3. The surplus is transferred only according to voters who expressed a preference as to where it should go. Seems fair to me! Voters had the option of whether they wanted to fill in 2,3,4 etc. and chose not to. I think on balance it's a good thing that if they do not give lower preferences then they don't control the surplus.
Well yeah! You have taken the non transferable votes and transferred them.4. Fewer votes go non-transferable and not effective.
But following on (1) they are probably not aware that they are missing out on the possible gearing up of their vote,5. Voters can, if they wish, express an indifference as to the destination of surplus votes, by only filling in no.1.
This is the fundamental error. Those who express a preference and are part of a transferable surplus will actually get more than the value of 1 vote. This is separate to the point that because of the physical process many people will get the value of 2 votes or even more, 1 for a person elected with a surplus and 1 for being lucky to be part of the random process of selecting the transfers. This is a separate point but the Scottish system which is part computerised doesn't even have this distortion.To reiterate too, under our system, everyone still has one vote, it is a single transferable vote. Your vote will rest with just one candidate in the end, always with a count value of 1.
To reiterate too, under our system, everyone still has one vote, it is a single transferable vote. Your vote will rest with just one candidate in the end, always with a count value of 1.
I think this is key. Let's take an example.To reiterate too, under our system, everyone still has one vote, it is a single transferable vote. Your vote will rest with just one candidate in the end, always with a count value of 1.
Using the above figures, the wrong candidate is elected.
View attachment 8952
B should have received only 500 votes and so their total would be 600, so c would have been elected without reaching the quota.
In the Irish system, each of those 200 remaining votes will continue into the church/gym pile as part of the surplus, same as it would if it was an open ballot.
In the Scottish system, even though were already at the quota, because 500 people are happy with either a church or a gym, 100 of the remaining 200 votes must go in the bin (despite those people having a clear preference for one or the other).
We all agree that A's votes should be reduced in some proportion on transfer to allow for the fact that A has already been elected.So the "correct" distribution method would have 70% of people who want absolutely nothing to do with C, yet them having 50% of the representation? C could never be elected by open ballot only by secret ballot.
You are advocating to discard valid preferential votes
The way I see it is that someone who voted A with a preference for B has not only had A elected but their full vote survives to elect someone else. So half of their vote elected A and their full vote survives. Looks like they got one and a half votes.
I think you are saying that the full vote of the non-transferable votes were used to elect A and the transferable votes had no part in electing A. That does not make sense to me and it clearly biases the transfers towards A's running mate.
Yes that explains the situation perfectly, though my correction makes it clearer that Group 2 is deemed not to have voted for A at all, with which I do see something wrong.In the example shown in post #89 there are:
1,000 votes which express a first preference for A and no second preference (Lets call them Group 1)
1,000 votes which express a first preference for A and a second preference for B (Lets call them Group 2)
I see nothing wrong with allocating Group 1 to A, andtransferringallocating all of Group 2 to B, which is the effect that the Irish system has.
The Scots which have come late to the party and can learn from precedent to not agree that there is something manifestly wrong. The "disenfranchisement" is that those who did not indicate a preference only got to use half their vote. Any system is full of this "disenftranchisement" through the elimination process. Group 1 get full value for their vote under the Scottish system - 0.5 in electing A 0.5 transferring to B.Running some alternative arrangement which allocates 1,000 votes to A and some (say 500 votes) to B and discards the balance is manifestly unfair and disenfranchises the last 500 voters.
A "represents" 2,000 voters.The actual effect of this is that A would now represents 1,500 voters, defeating the effect of the quota.
You can't transfer half a vote. Under STV, a vote is whole and indivisible no matter how you look at it.Group 1 get full value for their vote under the Scottish system - 0.5 in electing A 0.5 transferring to B.
That's a FPTP view. The STV as we use it introduced a transferable surplus to avoid this, which would otherwise amount to underrepresentation. A represents 1,000 voters and B represents 1,100 as her surplus cannot be transferred in this case.A "represents" 2,000 voters.
The physicals again - that is irrelevant. The Scottish deal in units of 1 in 10,000 but they do use a computer. The NI folk are manual but deal in .01 of a vote. Our Seanad actually deals in 100 units per vote.You can't transfer half a vote. Under STV, a vote is whole and indivisible no matter how you look at it.
So we agree that folk do get 1.5 votes in the example. For many that would be a showstopper.Is this not incidental to the process though? We have a minimum threshold, once a person passes that threshold, its not useful for people to keep telling me they like the guy whos already going to get a seat. I need to know who else is liked!
I think you mean a rolling ballot rather than a open one. Open suggests somehow more wholesome.C could never be elected by open ballot only by secret ballot.
We use cookies and similar technologies for the following purposes:
Do you accept cookies and these technologies?
We use cookies and similar technologies for the following purposes:
Do you accept cookies and these technologies?