‘Lifestyle’ Approach | Smoothed Approach | |
Total contribution (ratios 3:3:1 for employee, employer, and state) | 14% of earnings | 7% of earnings |
Gratuity on retirement at age 68 | 1½ times earnings | 1½ times earnings |
Yearly Pension from 68 to 90: | 50.2% of earnings | 53.8% of earnings |
Residual Fund at age 90: | 1.34 times earnings | 0.94 times earnings |
|
Good points SPC100. Some actuaries who support the thrust of the proposals feel that hard wiring the formula could be too rigid and that there should be scope to review it if circumstances change significantly. This point was made by the opener to the discussion, Seamus Creedon. The problem with making it even in principle open to review is that there would be an impetus for political pressures to do so if SV and MV get significantly out of kilter. Any review mechanism would need to have very clear manners put on it.It seems one of the big risks identified, especially for the future, when the fund is mature and may (will?) have more outflows than inflows, is if the smoothed value remains above the market value for an extended period of time. (this appeared to be the case in the 2 failures you identified in the talk). In particular if SV was ever > 233 when MV is 100, it would appear to not be rational for people to continue to invest, which could accerlate fund flow issues.
what patterns of market values can realistically result in elongated periods of time with SV above MV?
Have you considered complicating your smoothing function with an emergency hatch to reduce this risk? e.g. accelerate fater to the market value, if SV has been above MV by >p percent for n months.
At some point we have to accept the reality of market prices.
First of all, thanks for your constructive engagement, your good understanding of what I'm proposing, and your good questions.At some point we have to accept the reality of market prices.
I agree with your identification of the risks. I also have a lot of sympathy for your suggested solution. As @Duke of Marmalade writes, you are far from alone. If I were a prospective 'customer' of the scheme, however, I would be worried about joining a club where the rules could be changed if they weren't giving the right results. That is the main reason I am holding back from agreeing with you. I also believe that time is a great healer and a great solver of problems. We are all agreed that the problem we are discussing will not rear its head until cash flows turn negative. The model says that won't happen for 50 years. As I write in the paper, cash flows are likely to remain positive for even longer. I also believe that the buffer account will build up significantly over time. I am reasonably confident that the projection of 0.2% a year going to the buffer account from year 20 is an underestimate, that total costs will work out at less than 0.3% in the longer run, thus allowing more than 0.2% to go to the buffer account. The buffer account will also help a great deal when cash flows turn negative.It seems one of the big risks identified, especially for the future, when the fund is mature and may (will?) have more outflows than inflows, is if the smoothed value remains above the market value for an extended period of time. (this appeared to be the case in the 2 failures you identified in the talk). In particular if SV was ever > 233 when MV is 100, it would appear to not be rational for people to continue to invest, which could accerlate fund flow issues.
It depends on when market values fall. If they fall sharply in the early years, when cash is flooding in, then the smoothing formula can take nearly anything that is thrown at it. For example, in the 'adverse scenario' of Section 8 (a repeat of Japan from the start of 1990) market values fall 55% in the first three years, yet smoothed values are below market values at a dozen month ends in the first four years (see Section 12.11).what patterns of market values can realistically result in elongated periods of time with SV above MV?
This seems on the face of it to be an elegant attempt at a reworking of the old actuarial favourite a “with profits” fundI nearly wept this morning, hearing Regina Doherty on RTE with Rachel English, going over old ground of people having to decide whether they want to be low, medium or high risk; what happens if markets tumble on the day people retire; the carousel (probably one of the most ridiculous concepts ever devised); etc. I'm now absolutely convinced that the only way to avoid making a complete dog's dinner of AE is to adopt the smoothed, equity-based approach I've been advocating. A straightforward explanation can be found here. Additional papers and explanations can be found at http://www.colmfagan.ie/pensions.php
Unfortunately, it's proving difficult to get government, even my own profession, engaged. The prevailing view is that the proposals are too radical: "What you're proposing, Colm, hasn't been done anywhere else in the world; we don't want to be the first to try them out."
I’m personally getting 10%pa in my pension investing in residential social housing projects in the U.K. for example.
Hi @Marc, you're right that the smoothed approach to auto-enrolment and with profits share the same objective of allowing savers to enjoy the benefits of equity investment while protecting them from the associated volatility. There are some key differences, however, which mean that the smoothed approach to AE keeps the good parts of with-profits and ditches the bad parts.This seems on the face of it to be an elegant attempt at a reworking of the old actuarial favourite a “with profits” fund
Smoothed investment returns offer the appearance of a steady “bank interest” like return from an inherently volatile underlying capital asset like equites.
.... The problems with these policies are well documented. And in the extreme, Guaranteed annuity rates on pensions destroyed the once venerable Equitable Life.
Poorly understood “market value adjustments” and the need to pay zero bonuses and move the underlying assets into bonds following the tech bubble in the early noughties passed these products into what many of us hoped would be the history books.
And all in a single post!! I am impressed! But what does it all mean?philosopher Nassim Nicholas Taleb .... Gaussian (normal bell curve) ....Mandelbrot .... bell curve ... stochastic models .... Lévy stable process .... supported by Eugene Fama log-stable model .. better than .. lognormal .. tails too fat . portfolio theory ... Mandelbrot's stable distribution class ... Thaler .. behavioural finance ... Nobel Prize winner Bob Merton
Wow!! Lots in there, but I will focus in this post on the theme of the inappropriateness of the Normal model. I agree that it is absolutely crazy to use the Normal model for say daily price movements, though I understand that some quants did just that and it was a contributory factor in the GFC.This seems on the face of it to be an elegant attempt at a reworking of the old actuarial favourite a “with profits” fund
Smoothed investment returns offer the appearance of a steady “bank interest” like return from an inherently volatile underlying capital asset like equites.
Here the insurance company pretended to investors that equites don’t fluctuate and added a smoothed annual bonus to their policy. Once added these reversionary bonuses cannot be taken away. Investors also anticipated a terminal bonus on maturity.
The problems with these policies are well documented. And in the extreme, Guaranteed annuity rates on pensions destroyed the once venerable Equitable Life.
Poorly understood “market value adjustments” and the need to pay zero bonuses and move the underlying assets into bonds following the tech bubble in the early naughties passed these products into what many of us hoped would be the history books.
I was simply amazed that they were still being flogged by brokers when I arrived in Ireland in 2008.
Another example of a similar structure from an investor’s perspective is a defined benefit pension which protects the members pension at the expense of costs being born by the employer.
There was a joke in the City of London for many years that BA was a pension company that flew aeroplanes as hobby because the the hole in their defined benefit pension scheme.
In both these examples, the cost of meeting the contractual commitments were too high to bear from either a prudent regulatory capital perspective for the life insurance industry or in the corporate world.
Many States around the world also have a history of offering a universal retirement saving scheme in the form of social security and state pensions.
Here again experience has shown that the cost of providing a universal retirement income, albeit on an unfunded basis, is too high and many countries have sought to address the increased costs from rising life expectancies by pushing back the retirement age.
We saw in France only recently how attempts to manage these costs are sometimes met by the public.
In Ireland, of course, the state also has another unfunded liability in the form of the public sector pension liability which I was reliably told many years ago was already standing at twice the liability arising from the bail out of the banks in the financial crisis.
Under the conditions that the Life Cos, the Corporate Sector and States generally have all struggled and, to a greater or lesser extent failed, to underwrite the increasing costs being incurred by an aging population i’m hardly surprised it’s a difficult sell to expect a politician to sign up to underwriting a guarantee that an entire countries retirement savings could be linked to global capital markets and the risk of a collapse underwritten by the State.
How likely is a very significant shock to capital markets? If stock returns were normally distributed a 40% decline as we saw in the financial crisis should be expected as normal in capital markets and should occur on average around 2.5% of the time or one year in 40.
But stock returns aren’t even normally distributed and “fat tails” are a feature of capital markets.
The worst year on record for the US market was in the early 1930s during the Great Depression when the US market dropped by around two thirds.
Rare events whilst improbable are not impossible and failing to account for extreme market conditions blew up both LTCM and Lehmans.
“Consider the stock market collapse during the Russian bond default of August 1998. On 4 August the Dow fell 3.5% and, three weeks later, as the news worsened, stock fell again, by 4.4%, and then again, on the 31 August, by 6.8%.
Theory would estimate the odds of that final 31 August collapse at one in 20 million – an event which, were you to trade daily for almost 100,000 years, you would not expect to see even once. The odds of getting three such declines in the same month were about one in 500 billion.
A year earlier, the Dow had fallen 7.7% in one day (probability: one in 50 billion). In July, 2002, the index recorded three steep falls within seven trading days (probability: one in four trillion). And on 19 October 1987, the worst day of trading in at least a century, the index fell 29.2%. The probability of that happening, according to orthodox financial theory, was less than one in 10 to the 50, odds so small they have no meaning, and are beyond the scale of nature.
You could search for powers of ten from the smallest sub-atomic particle to the breadth of the observable universe and still never meet such a number.”
Recently the philosopher Nassim Nicholas Taleb in his book The Black Swan has attacked the use of Gaussian (normal bell curve) mathematics as the foundation of finance.
Taleb is a fan of Mandelbrot, whose mathematics account for fat tails. He argues that the bell curve doesn't reflect reality and this means stochastic models for market returns are more complicated.
In 1963, Mandelbrot modelled cotton prices with a Lévy stable process, and his finding was later supported by Eugene Fama in 1965.
The S&P 500 has suffered 10 monthly returns worse than three standard deviations below its mean.
The log-stable model does a better job of capturing the S&P 500’s extremes than the lognormal model, but its tails are too fat.
As I have shown, seeking to mix capital guarantees of any sort and inherently volatile capital assets has a history of bad outcomes.
However, whilst the short-term distribution of capital market returns can sink anyone trying to underwrite a guarantee, for the long term passive investor we can choose to ignore the short term noise.
“We agree that Mandelbrot is right. As we can see when looking at the daily market returns, the distribution is fat-tailed relative to the normal distribution.
In other words, extreme returns occur much more often than would be expected if returns were normal.
However most of what we do in terms of portfolio theory and models of risk and expected return works for Mandelbrot's stable distribution class, as well as for the normal distribution.
Our conclusion is that for long-term passive investors, the short term
distribution doesn’t matter beyond being aware that outlier returns are more common than would be expected if return distributions were normal.”
Eugene F Fama
In other words smoothing of investment returns isn’t required for investment reasons and adds unnecessary complexity. It’s required for emotional and psychological reasons to address our innate tendency towards loss aversion. And that leads us on to the field of behavioural finance.
Thaler and others in the behavioural finance world have shown that auto enrolment works mainly due to the nudge effect of having to opt out rather than opt in.
The lions share of the “issue” here is the lack of universal coverage in private pension provision in excess of social security. Many people are not saving for their retirement and have little more than the basic state pension to see them through.
This part of the puzzle isn’t an investment problem at all but rather a question of how a civilised society should provide for people in old age.
Governments could simply increase PRSI. (This article supports this line of reasoning.https://www.irishtimes.com/politics/2023/05/10/windfall-tax-receipts-will-not-be-enough-to-cover-cost-of-ageing-population/) and increase the basic state pension but that is a vote losing increase in tax which would benefit everyone equally and some need the additional pension more than others.
“Making” (they can opt out) people save for their retirement is a form of tax by another name.
Even if the returns on these saving are only equal to inflation that is still slightly better from the perspective of the both the state and the investor than an unfunded liability.
Published work on this subject can be found by Nobel Prize winner Bob Merton who concluded that an intermediate term inflation linked bond would do the job pretty well.
I’ll end with a philosophical question: why isn’t the underlying investment for auto enrolment directly invested by NTMA?
Contributions, or at least some of the contributions, could be used for publicly funded infrastructure projects. And, this doesn’t have to mean much lower returns for investors.
I’m personally getting 10%pa in my pension investing in residential social housing projects in the U.K. for example.
If people were shown how their contributions were being invested to address issues here in Ireland like homelessness, climate change, poor provision of services to people with disabilities or whatever social or environmental issues you might care to list rather than further boosting the profits of US multinationals they might be more willing to get behind it.
But as I sort of alluded to earlier isn’t that also why we pay taxes?
These are precisely Colm's arguments. Colm sees pension provision as a whole life investment where the "short term distribution doesn't matter". But he does put more store on the behavioural dimension that you refer to. He sees lifestyling as being a slave to this behaviour. One approach, which it seems you are advocating is that people just let it run and ignore the short term volatility. Colm's approach takes the behavioural aspect somewhat more seriously and actually provides concrete solace to those who would not be convinced by your argument that it will all be alright on the night. There is also an element of substance rather than mere optics in Colm's suggestion as it would involve an element of cross cohort volatility pooling. Your post also refers to the complexity of Colm's proposal. I think you are misunderstanding his proposal. He envisages, say quarterly, declarations of "interest" applicable to all accounts rather than daily unit pricing. He argues that it could be implemented even quicker than what is currently proposed.Marc #70 said:However, whilst the short-term distribution of capital market returns can sink anyone trying to underwrite a guarantee, for the long term passive investor we can choose to ignore the short term noise.
...
Our conclusion is that for long-term passive investors, the short term
distribution doesn’t matter beyond being aware that outlier returns are more common than would be expected if return distributions were normal.
In other words smoothing of investment returns isn’t required for investment reasons and adds unnecessary complexity. It’s required for emotional and psychological reasons to address our innate tendency towards loss aversion. And that leads us on to the field of behavioural finance.